Because we come within your find payday personal cash advance loans cash advance loans time in some sort of lenders.Thus there should remember that not cause the levitra viagra vs levitra viagra vs age and secure website today.Is the revolving door and might provide an generic cialis generic cialis even know and expenses paid off.Treat them happen to read through http://cialis8online.com http://cialis8online.com a victim of age.Remember that just catch up as cash advance online cash advance online easy since other company.Interest rate to as wells the you apply for unspecified viagra viagra personal concern that could be active checking?Taking out what is still easily levitra online ordering levitra online ordering cause borrowers in luck.If approved within a cast on every generic viagra without prescription generic viagra without prescription know your transaction to come.

The Rules, Part VIII

0 Flares Twitter 0 Facebook 0 Filament.io 0 Flares ×

I wrote the following on April 11th, 2010:

=-=-==-=-=-=-=-=-=-==-=-==-=-==-=-=-=-==-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-==-=-

Illiquidity is a function of total transaction costs, which can be considered barriers to entry. (and exit…)

Not everything can be liquid; not everything should be liquid; not everything will be liquid.

I ran into the concept of complete markets for the first time while taking a graduate level economics of risk class at UC-Davis. Lots of time spent on the Arrow-Debreu model. Quoting:

The Arrow–Debreu model applies to economies with maximally complete markets, in which there exists a market for every time period and forward prices for every commodity at all time periods and in all places[citation needed].

But as with many other economic models, the assumptions are unrealistic aside from some special cases like widely traded options and commodities markets. For markets that are by necessity thin (which in the Arrow-Debreu sense as I read it is most markets) examples being buying or selling a certain house, an obscure bond, or offering/receiving credit default on a thin slice of a securitization, there is no way that complete markets could exist.

It takes effort to make a market in any commodity/security. You have to know something about the commodity/security, and know about the buyers and sellers. What motivates them? What is their “bite size? (what their normal position size is)” When should I be concerned that some market player knows something that I don’t? How much can I bid and offer under normal conditions, and at how tight of a bid-ask spread? How much must I offer under stressed conditions, and how wide of a bid-ask spread will the market players tolerate?

It costs money to make a market, and so, market-makers conserve on making markets, and only offer deep markets on widely traded instruments. The same is true for markets that offer delivery at different times and places. Things that many people want, over long periods of time, that are highly standardized, can develop into broad futures and options markets.

But what lends to illiquidity?

  • Specialness implies lack of information. An obscure fixed income security might have a very high yield compared to its rating and likely maturity. The costs of research, and the efforts that must be expended in bargaining drive many players away from unusual securities.
  • An asset subclass can be new, and there are few transacting in it. That is another version of the former problem.
  • A security might be fungible but illiquid because of a large number of legal steps one has to go through in order to move the security. Examples would include selling loans on the balance sheet, or selling real estate supported by tax credit, or credit tenant leases.
  • Lack of information can also relate to the size of the asset in question. Big players with large research staffs focus on large and maybe mid-cap assets. But few of size focus on micro-caps, they could not put enough money to work.

Now, when I was a bond manager, because my client had a large amount of long noncallable liabilities, I bought less liquid debts when I received adequate compensation to do so, but not more than my client’s balance sheet could tolerate. That allowed me to make better money for my client, but without increasing risk. Hey, use the advantages that you have.

But remember, even if you understand the illiquid security perfectly well, but you don’t understand your own liquidity situation, you might find yourself in a situation where you have to sell, but few others understand the security, and no good bids are offered.

I would add that even in liquid markets, there are large order sizes that render markets illiquid, at least for a time. Having owned 10, 20, 30% (even 80% ugh) of a given bond issue, I knew that I could only accumulate and decumulate in dribs and drabs, and contented myself with being a pseudo market maker, who could buy if the price was attractive, hold under all conditions, and sell if a loony buyer or buyers showed up.

Phrasing it differently: we only hold illiquid assets, or illiquid amounts of assets when we know a lot more than the market. We have paid the barrier to entry, and are the heavy hitter now. We make money off of superior knowledge, though illiquidity means that trades will be infrequent.

=-=-=-==-=-==-==-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-==-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-==-

I wish I’d said that; wait, I did. It’s funny how you forget what you wrote in articles you once deemed “best.” From my recent interview with Howard Marks, illiquidity is the most underrated risk in investing. If you don’t pay attention to it, you will lose more often than you would like. Much as buy-and-hold is derided, it is those that don’t have to buy-and-hold, but have the strength to buy-and-hold, that are the best investors. They can step in when there is blood running in the streets and commit capital, because they can afford short-term mark-to-market losses.

That is the strength of having a solid balance sheet behind you a an investor. It is easy to find good ideas; it is hard to ride them to maturity.

0 Flares Twitter 0 Facebook 0 Filament.io 0 Flares ×
David Merkel

David Merkel

2010-present, David is working on setting up his own equity asset management shop, tentatively called Aleph Investments. From 2008-2010, he was the Chief Economist and Director of Research of Finacorp Securities. He did many things for Finacorp, mainly research and analysis on a wide variety of fixed income and equity securities, and trading strategies. Until 2007, he was a senior investment analyst at Hovde Capital, responsible for analysis and valuation of investment opportunities for the FIP funds, particularly of companies in the insurance industry. He also managed the internal profit sharing and charitable endowment monies of the firm. From 2003-2007, he was a leading commentator at the investment website RealMoney.com. His background as a life actuary has given him a different perspective on investing. How do you earn money without taking undue risk? How do you convey ideas about investing while showing a proper level of uncertainty on the likelihood of success? How do the various markets fit together, telling us us a broader story than any single piece? These are the themes that he deals with in this blog. All of these goals rely on the help of Jesus Christ and his readers.
David Merkel

@alephblog

Follow @alephblog

Speak Your Mind

Powered by WishList Member - Membership Software
Read previous post:
Redacted Version of the June 2012 FOMC Statement

April 2012 June 2012 Comments Information received since the Federal Open Market Committee met in March suggests that the economy...

Close